We show that the set of priors in the representation of Choquet expectation is the one of equivalent martingale measures under some conditions, when given capacity is submodular. It is proven via Peng’s
g
-expectation and related topics.
1. INTRODUCTION
A starting point for a mathematical definition of risk is simply as standard deviation. The more risk we take, the more we stand to lose or gain. Standard deviation (or volatility) is a kind of simple risk measure. Different families of risk measures have been proposed in literature like coherent, convex, spectral risk measures, conditional value-at-risk etc. and discussed to measure or quantify the market risks in theoretical and practical perspectives. Risk measures are also linked to insurance premiums.
Markowitz
[18]
used the standard deviation to measure the market risk in his portfolio theory but his method doesn’t tell the difference between the positive and the negative deviation. Artzer et al.
[1
,
2]
proposed a coherent risk measure in an axiomatic approach, and formulated the representation theorems. Fritelli
[11]
proposed sublinear risk measure to weaken coherent axioms. Heath
[14]
firstly studied the convex risk measures and Föllmer & Schied
[8
,
9
,
10]
and Frittelli & Rosazza Gianin
[12]
extended them to general probability spaces. They had weakened the conditions of positive homogeneity and subadditivity by replacing them with convexity.
There exist stochastic phenomena like Allais paradox and Ellsberg paradox which can not be dealt with linear mathematical expectation in economics. So Choquet
[4]
introduced a nonlinear expectation called Choquet expectation which applied to many areas such as statistics, economics and finance. Choquet expectation is equivalent to the convex(or coherent) risk measure if given capacity is submodular. But Choquet expectation has a difficulty in defining a conditional expectation. Peng
[21]
introduced a nonlinear expectation,
g
-expectation which is a solution of a nonlinear backward stochastic differential equation. It’s easy to define conditional expectation with Peng’s
g
-expectation (see papers
[5
,
13
,
15
,
17
,
20
,
22]
for related topics).
In this paper, we show that the set of priors in the representation of Choquet expectation is the one of equivalent martingale measures under some conditions, when the distortion is submodular. That is, if a capacity
c
is submodular, then we have the representation
where
Qc
:= {
Q
∈
M
1,f
:
Q
[
A
] ≤
c
(
A
) ∀
A
∈
FT
}. There is no specific explanation in the literature for the structure of the set
Qc
. It is worthy of examining it. By using
g
-expectation and related topics, we’ll show that
for some density generator set Θ
g
.
This paper consists of as follows. Introduction is given in section 1. Definitions of Choquet expectation( or integral) and risk measures are stated in section 2. Definition of Peng’s
g
-expectation and related topics are given in section 3. The set of priors in the representation of Choquet expectation is discussed and the main Theorem 4.4 is given in section 4.
2. DEFINITIONS OF CHOQUET EXPECTATION( OR INTEGRAL) AND RISK MEASURES
In this section, we give definitions of Choquet expectation( or integral) and coherent( or convex) risk measures. Let (Ω,(
Ft
)
t∈[0,T]
,
P
) be the given filtered probability space.
Definition 2.1.
A set function
c
:
F
→ [0, 1] is called
monotone
if
and normalized if
The monotone and normalized set function is called a
capacity
. A monotone set function is called
submodular
or 2-
alternating
if
Two real functions
X
and
Y
defined on Ω are called
comonotonic
if
A class of function
X
is said to be comonotonic if for every pair (
X
,
Y
) ∈
X
×
X
,
X
and
Y
are comonotonic.
Definition 2.2.
Let
ψ
: [0, 1] → [0, 1] be increasing function with
ψ
(0) = 0 and
ψ
(1) = 1. The set function
is called
distortion
of
P
with respect to the distortion function
ψ
.
The
cψ
defined in Definition 2.2 becomes normalized monotone function. The notion of integral with respect to a capacity is due to Choquet
[4]
.
Definition 2.3.
Let
c
:
F
→ [0, 1] be monotone and normalized set function. The
Choquet integral
or
concave distortion risk
measure of
X
∈
L
2
(
FT
) with respect to
c
is defined as
The following is the definition of coherent risk measure of which concept is borrowed from one of norm.
Definition 2.4.
A
coherent risk measure
ρ
:
X
→ ℝ is a mapping satisfying for
X
,
Y
∈
X
(1)
ρ
(
X
) ≥
ρ
(
Y
) if
X
≤
Y
(monotonicity),
(2)
ρ
(
X
+
m
) =
ρ
(
X
) −
m
for
m
∈ ℝ (translation invariance),
(3)
ρ
(
X
+
Y
) ≤
ρ
(
X
) +
ρ
(
Y
) (subadditivity),
(4)
ρ
(
λX
) =
λρ
(
X
) for
λ
≥ 0 (positive homogeneity).
The subadditivity and the positive homogeneity can be relaxed to a weaker quantity, i.e. convexity
which means
diversification
should not increase the risk.
A
convex risk measure
ρ
:→ ℝ is a functional satisfying monotonicity, translation invariance and convexity.
Definition 2.5.
Choquet integral of the loss is defined as
where
c
is a capacity.
Choquet integral of the loss
ρ
:
X
→ ℝ satisfies monotonicity, cash invariance, positive homogeneity and the others.
(1)
∫
λdc
=
λ
for constant
λ
(constant preserving).
(2) If
X
≤
Y
, then
∫
(−
X
)
dc
≥
∫
(−
Y
)
dc
(monotonicity).
(3) For
λ
≥ 0,
∫
λ
(−
X
)dc =
λ
∫
(−
X
)
dc
(positive homogeneity).
(4) If
X
and
Y
are comonotone functions, then
.
(5) If
c
is submodular or concave function, then
3. PENG’S G-EXPECTATION
In this section, the definition of g-expectation is given. Let
g
: Ω×[0,
T
]×ℝ×ℝ
n
→ ℝ be a function that
g
↦
g
(
t
,
y
,
z
) is measurable for each (
y
,
z
) ∈ ℝ×ℝ
n
and satisfy the following conditions
Theorem 3.1
(
[21]
)
.
For every terminal condition
ξ
∈
L
2
(
FT
) :=
L
2
(Ω,
FT
,
P
)
the following backward stochastic differential equation
has a unique solution
Definition 3.2.
For each
ξ
∈
L
2
(
FT
) and for each
t
∈ [0,
T
]
g
−expectation of
X
and the conditional
g
−expectation of
X
under
Ft
is respectively defined by
where
yt
is the solution of the BSDE (3.2).
3.1. Two sets of probability measures,
and
Let
g
be independent of
y
and
g
(
t
,
y
, 0) = 0. We define two sets of probability measures on the measurable space (Ω,
FT
),
where
t
∈ [0,
T
] and Θ
g
is defined as
Let’s see properties of set of priors,
Qc
as in (1.1). Set
Then
is a
P
-martingale since
. Also
is a
P
-density on
FT
since
. A probability measure
Qθ
on (Ω,
F
) is equivalent to
P
, where
Qθ
is defined as
We can easily see that
Qc
is convex and weakly compact in
L
1
(Ω,
F
,
P
). For every deterministic
τ
∈ [0,
T
] and every
B
∈
Fτ
,
where
denotes the restriction of
Q
3
to
Fτ
(See the paper
[23]
for details).
If
θ
∈ Θ
g
, i.e.
θt
·
z
≤
g
(
t
,
z
), then we have
θt
·
z
≤ |
g
(
t
,
z
)| ≤
K
|
z
| and so |
θt
| ≤
K
by taking
z
=
θt
. The Girsanov transformation implies that there exists a probability measure
Qθ
on the space (Ω,
Ft
) such that
and
,
t
∈ [0,
T
] is a
Qθ
-Brownian motion.
The two prior sets,
and
are the same set under some conditions.
Theorem 3.3
(
[16]
)
.
Let g be independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). Then
Definition 3.4.
Let
g
be independent of
y
and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). The generator
g
is said to be
sublinear
with respect to
z
if for
a
≥ 0,
z
1
,
z
2
∈ ℝ
d
Theorem 3.5
(
[16]
)
.
Let g be independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). Then
∀
ξ
∈
L
2
(Ω,
Ft
,
P
)
if and only if g is sublinear with respect to z
.
4. THE SET OF PRIORS IN THE REPRESENTATION OF CHOQUET EXPECTATION
The following theorem is about the equivalent properties on the Choquet integral with respect to a capacity
c
.
Theorem 4.1
(
[7]
)
.
For the Choquet integral with respect to a capacity c, the followings are equivalent
.
(1)
ρ
(
X
) :=
∫
(−
X
)
dc is a convex risk measure on
L
2
(
FT
).
(2)
ρ
(
X
) :=
∫
(−
X
)
dc is a coherent risk measure on
L
2
(
FT
).
(3)
For
Qc
:= {
Q
∈
M
1,f
:
Q
[
A
] ≤
c
(
A
) ∀
A
∈
FT
},
where
M
1,f
:=
M
1,f
(Ω,
F
)
is the set of all finitely additive normalized set functions
Q
:
F
→ [0, 1].
(4)
The set function c is submodular
.
In this case
,
Qc
=
Qmax
,
where
Qmax
:= {
Q
≪
P
:
αmin
(
Q
) = 0}
is in the representation of the convex risk measure
Peng’s g-expectation provides various features. We will use the properties of g-expectation to investigate the set of prior,
Qc
. The classical mathematical expectation can be represented by the Choquet expectation if
g
is linear function of
z
. The following theorem deals with the one-dimensional Brownian motion case, and
y
,
z
∈ ℝ.
Theorem 4.2
(
[3]
)
.
Suppose that g satisfies the conditions (3.1a), (3.1b) and (3.1c)
.
Then there exists a Choquet expectation whose restriction to
L
2
(Ω,
F
,
P
)
is equal to a g-expectation if and only if g is independent of y and is linear in z, i.e. there exists a continuous function
νt
such that
Set
g
(
y
,
z
,
t
) =
νtz
through the last of this paper. Then Choquet expectation is equal to
g
-expectation by Theorem 4.2. I.e., there exist a capacity
cg
such that
If we take
ξ
=
IA
for
A
∈
F
in (4.2), then the capacity
cg
satisfies
Then we can prove that
cg
is submodular.
Theorem 4.3.
The capacity cg in (4.2) is submodular
.
Proof
. By Dellacherie’s theorem in Dellacherie
[6]
, Choquet expectation on
L
2
(Ω,
F
,
P
) is comonotonic additive. That is, if
Ɛg
is Choquet expectation, then we have
Ɛg
[
ξ
+
η
] =
Ɛg
[
ξ
] +
Ɛg
[
η
] whenever
ξ
and
η
are comonotonic.
Note that
I
A∪B
and
I
A∩B
is a pair of comonotone functions for all
A
,
B
∈
F
. Hence comonotonicity and subadditivity of
Ɛg
imply
So the proof is done. ☐
Since
cg
is submodular, by Theorem 4.1 we have the representation
where
Qcg
:= {
Q
∈
M
1,f
:
Q
[
A
] ≤
cg
(
A
) ∀
A
∈
FT
}.
The following is the main theorem.
Theorem 4.4.
where
Qcg
is the prior set in the representation (4.3)
.
Notice that
is defined as
where
t
∈ [0,
T
] and Θ
g
is defined as
Proof
. Since
has the same expression as
becomes
Qcg
. Since
g
(
y
,
z
,
t
) =
νtz
is independent of
y
and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c),
=
by Theorem 3.3. Therefore, we have
. ☐
In fact, for the linear function
g
(
t
,
y
,
z
) =
νtz
, let us consider the BSDE
The above differential equation (4.4) is reduced to
By Girsanov’s Theorem,
-Brownian motion under
Qν
defined as
Therefore we have the relations
which means
g
-expectation is a classical mathematical expectation.
Acknowledgements
This work was supported by the research grant of Sungshin Women’s University in 2015.
Artzner P.
,
Delbaen F.
,
Eber J.-M.
,
Heath D.
(1989)
Heath: Thinking coherently
Risk
10
68 -
71
Artzner P.
,
Delbaen F.
,
Eber J.-M.
,
Heath D.
(1999)
Heath: Coherent measures of risk
Mathematical Finance
9
203 -
223
DOI : 10.1111/1467-9965.00068
Choquet G.
(1953)
Theory of capacities
Ann. Inst. Fourier (Grenoble)
5
131 -
195
Coquet F.
,
Hu Y.
,
Mémin J.
,
Peng S.
(2002)
Filtration consistent nonlinear expectations and related g-expectations
Probability Theory and Related Fields
123
1 -
27
DOI : 10.1007/s004400100172
Dellacherie C.
1970
Quelques commentaires sur les prolongements de capacités. Séminaire de Probabilités V. Strasbourg
Springer
Lecture Notes in Math.
191
77 -
81
Föllmer H.
,
Schied A.
2002
Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time
Springer-Verlag
New York
Föllmer H.
,
Schied A.
(2002)
Convex measures of risk and trading constraints
Finance & Stochastics
6
429 -
447
DOI : 10.1007/s007800200072
Föllmer H.
,
Schied A.
,
Sandmann K.
,
Schönbucher P.J.
Robust preferences and convex measures of risk
Springer-Verlag
Advances in Finance and Stochastics
Föllmer H.
,
Schied A.
2004
Stochastic Finance: An introduction in discrete time
Walter de Gruyter
Berlin
Frittelli M.
2000
Representing sublinear risk measures and pricing rules
http://www.mat.unimi.it/users/frittelli/pdf/Sublinear2000.pdf
He K.
,
Hu M.
,
Chen Z.
(2009)
The relationship between risk measures and Choquet expectations in the framework of g-expectations
Statistics and Probability Letters
79
508 -
512
DOI : 10.1016/j.spl.2008.09.025
Heath D.
2000
Back to the future. Plenary lecture at the First World Congress of the Bachelier Society
Paris
Jiang L.
(2006)
Convexity, translation invariance and subadditivity for g-expectation and related risk measures
Annals of Applied Provability
18
245 -
258
Jiang L.
(2009)
A necessary and sufficient condition for probability measures dominated by g-expectation
Statistics and Probability Letters
79
196 -
201
DOI : 10.1016/j.spl.2008.07.037
El Karoui N.
,
Peng S.G.
,
Quenez M.-C.
(1997)
Quenez: Backward stochastic differential equations in finance
Math. Finance
7
1 -
71
DOI : 10.1111/1467-9965.00022
Markowitz H.
(1952)
Portfolio selection
The Journal of Finance
26
1443 -
1471
Peng S.
(1997)
Backward SDE and related g-expectation, backward stochastic DEs
Pitman
364
141 -
159
Peng S.
,
El Karoui N.
,
Mazliak L.
(1997)
Backward SDE and related g-expectations, in: Backward stochastic differential equations
Pitman Res. Notes Math. Ser.
364
141 -
159
Chen Zengjing
,
Epstein Larry
(2002)
Ambiguity, risk and asset returns in continuous time
Econometrica
70
1403 -
1443
DOI : 10.1111/1468-0262.00337